top of page
Writer's pictureMarco Schito

Public Policy Series: Beyond National Public Policy

Foreword


Public policies are everywhere in today’s world, but their ubiquity is also why their definition is often elusive and the analysis of public policies tends to be complex. The Public Policy series offers the reader several tools of analysis that help make sense of the complexity of public policies. This series comprises eight different articles, each focusing on a different aspect, which should provide the reader with a framework of analysis to better understand the complex world of public policy-making.

The focus of this series so far has been on national public policy. When policy decisions involve actors and institutions hailing from different contexts, policy-making takes on the name of ‘multi-level governance’ (see Marks, 1993; Hooghe & Marks, 2003). Multi-level governance (henceforth MLG) can go both from national to sub-national, such as in federal systems, and from national to supra-national, which is the case of the European Union (EU). Understanding MLG arrangements is necessary to explain how policy comes to be when there are multiple levels of decision-making, each involving different sets of actors, often with diverging interests.


Scholars offered several different definitions of MLG. For instance, Marks (1993: 392) understands it as ‘[a] system of continuous negotiation among nested governments at several territorial levels.’ Rhodes (1997: 1) suggests that we ‘no longer have a mono-centric or unitary government,’ and that there are ‘many centres linking many levels of government,’ from local to supranational. Finally, Richards and Smith (2004) claim that policy-making has become a complex mix of hierarchies, networks and markets, characterised by dispersal of authority and of decision-making.


Cairney (2019) identifies three key ideas behind MLG. Firstly, MLG can be a choice, as is the case of the EU (membership to which is voluntary), or of countries such as Switzerland and Germany, both of which allow a strong level of autonomy to their regions (the Swiss Canton and the German Länder). On the opposite end there are systems of governance such as the British Westminster model, where a strong, centralised state acts unilaterally in matters of policy-making (on this, see Rhodes, 1997). However, MLG can also be a necessity. This is particularly the case in federal polities such as the United States, Canada, Australia, or India, whose extensive territory and heterogeneous population make unitary state arrangements contentious or difficult to manage (Kelemen, 2000; see also Fabbrini, 2010).



Figure 1: Shutterstock (2020). The US is the oldest example of a system of multilevel governance. [Illustration]. Governing.

The second key idea behind MLG is that of power-sharing. Having multiple centres of governance and overlapping competencies can lead to coordination problems. Indeed, it is not uncommon for MLG systems to fall into the so-called ‘joint decision trap’ (Scharpf, 1988), in which the eventual policy outcome can only be taken at the lowest common denominator in order to satisfy all actors. Unfortunately, this often results in a slow, piecemeal and unambitious policy. The problem is particularly complex when one or more actors have veto power over the decision-making process (see Tsebelis, 1995, 2002). This is for instance the case for several EU policies such as membership approval and foreign affairs: in such instances, one single member state can block the entire process, further lowering the bar for the lowest common denominator.


On the other hand, MLG arrangements can also work as a conduit of easier policy diffusion and transfer (on this, see Dolowitz & Marsh, 2000; Simmons et al., 2006). Being part of the same community (whether federal or supranational) can improve policy-makers’ ability to learn from past policies in a similar environment and implement them at a new level of governance. This was the case for healthcare in the United States. Barack Obama’s Affordable Care Act was an improved version of an earlier experiment for expanded healthcare access in the State of Massachusetts. Likewise, the Covid-19 pandemic allowed national leaders to more easily observe how well different levels of restrictions worked both in other EU member states and within subnational units, which made their choice about national-level restrictions easier to weigh against other policies on the table.


The final idea behind MLG is that it is also a new way to understand policy-making. The standard policy cycle heuristic is often difficult to apply in multi-level systems of governance. For instance, in the EU, the Commission holds agenda-setting power (Nugent & Rhinard, 2015); policy is often formulated with the help of transnational interest groups (Klüver, 2013); decision-making power is shared between the member states, represented at the Council, and nationally elected Members of the European Parliament (Hix & Høyland, 2011); implementation is also a multilevel problem-solving game involving European institutions, national-level ministries and local implementing officers (Börzel et al., 2010; Thomann, 2019). In such a conundrum, the policy cycle heuristic becomes even messier and more abstracted from reality.


Figure 2: Flickr (n.d.). It's difficult to explain European public policy-making without making any reference to MLG. [Photography].

On the contrary, an approach based on MLG, which can take into account policy learning and diffusion both by policy issue and over time, is better able to capture the development of European integration, and why the EU went from a relatively simple and small economic agreement limited to regulatory policies (Majone, 1994, 1996) to a quasi-federal political arrangement, with a complicated web of institutions (Fabbrini, 2015; Coman et al., 2020). It can also help explain why some policies such as consumer protection have enjoyed widespread success when implemented at the European level (Rauh, 2019), whereas others such as debt mutualisation have found much more resistance (Howarth & Schild, 2021).


It should not be surprising, then, that MLG, especially pertaining to the development of the EU, has deep roots. The first theoreticians of European integration adduced two potential lines of development for the EU (back then still European Economic Community). One theory, neofunctionalism, was supported by Ernst Haas (1958, 1961) and suggested that transnational economic interests would be the driving force behind stronger integration. Businesses at the national level would see economic integration as a strong incentive to switch from national- to EU-based regulation, thus pushing policy-making beyond the national boundaries. On the opposite side, intergovernmentalists such as Stanley Hoffman (1966; and later Andrew Moravcsik, 1993, 1998), rebutted this claim by showing how the development of EU integration was stunted by national interests, which did not want to lose sovereignty. Putnam (1988) later suggested that political actors may be playing a 'two-level game' in which receiving concessions at the higher level (the EU, for instance) would be easier when the more constrained leaders were at the lower level (the national level).


Although none of these scholars explicitly addressed these processes as MLG, they were, for all intents and purposes, describing its modus operandi. Neo-functionalism showed how policy learning would be easier within a common regulatory framework. For its part, intergovernmentalism suggested that strong veto players would inevitably lead EU policy-making within a 'joint-decision trap', denying any possibility of further developments at the higher level. Putnam's (1988) claim was that this was not a foregone conclusion, but that policy negotiations (i.e. the formulation and decision stage) at the EU level would depend on individual national situations. Today, MLG scholars accept that all such takes are valid, which ironically creates a paradox: on the one hand, national states are conducive to better EU-level policy-making as they help in aggregating the preferences of their citizens beyond the national borders, on the other, they often constrain EU policy-making on grounds of national sovereignty (Schackel et al., 2015).


Figure 3: Murphy, M. (2021). Britain has lost the EU. Can it find a role?. [Illustration]. The Economist.

The main issue relating to MLG is that it remains an elusive concept even among scholars. There is a wide consensus that today’s policy-making process has changed extensively, and that a variety of political actors from the sub-national, national, and supranational levels alike are getting involved in shaping policy outcomes. However, a MLG approach is very difficult to apply to policy studies in a coherent and systematic manner. Such difficulty stems from three factors. First, since MLG can be applied to a wide range of systems of governance, there lack clear definitional characteristics that can be related to all MLG arrangements.


Secondly, MLG can often be chaotic, and competencies among jurisdictions at different levels are often blurred, leading to several contentions before courts (one only needs to think of the long list of complaints before the US Supreme Court concerning the competence of the States versus the federal government). Inevitably, this adds to the previous definitional problems, leading different scholars to understand the same MLG arrangement in different ways. Indeed, as Schackel et al. (2015) write, ‘there are almost as many definitions of MLG as there are users of the term.’



Figure 4: Mitchell, J. J. (2022). People manifesting in favour of Scottish independence, which would end its devolution relationship with Westminster [Photograph]. The Times.

Finally, polities can present elements of both typical unitary and federal systems. For instance, the United Kingdom is often understood as a strong centralised state, in which the dispersion of formal authority is limited to a small number of jurisdictions through devolution (Scotland, Northern Ireland, and Wales). However, responsibilities between these jurisdictions and Westminster often overlap, leading to devolved and central governments producing different policy instruments to deal with the same problem (see Bache & Flinders, 2004).


Notwithstanding these weaknesses, the idea of MLG governance should not be discarded. Rather, as Cairney (2019) points out, it remains extremely useful to understand policy-making, in at least two ways. First, it can be employed conceptually, as an abstract way to describe key policy-making developments. This is the case of the joint decision trap, which could not be explained by single-level governance approaches. Secondly, it can be employed to describe specific empirical developments, such as how certain policy areas, e.g. monetary policy, have undergone a process of Europeanisation (on monetary policy, see Mourlon-Druol, 2012; see also Börzel, 2005 for multiple policies comparison), leading to the creation of new European institutions and policies.


Bibliographical References:


Bache, I., & Flinders, M. (2004). Multi-level governance and the study of the British state. Public policy and administration, 19(1), 31-51.


Börzel, T. A. (2005). Mind the gap! European integration between level and scope. Journal of European Public Policy, 12(2), 217-236.


Börzel, T. A., Hofmann, T., Panke, D., & Sprungk, C. (2010). Obstinate and inefficient: Why member states do not comply with European law. Comparative political studies, 43(11), 1363-1390.


Cairney, P. (2019). Understanding Public Policy. 2nd edition. London: Red Globe Press.


Coman, R., Crespy, A., & Schmidt, V. A. (Eds.). (2020). Governance and politics in the post-crisis European Union. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.


Dolowitz, D. P., & Marsh, D. (2000). Learning from abroad: The role of policy transfer in contemporary policy‐making. Governance, 13(1), 5-23.


Fabbrini, S. (2010). Compound democracies: Why the United States and Europe are becoming similar. Oxford: Oxford University Press.


Fabbrini, S. (2015). Which European Union?. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.


Haas, E. B. (1958). Uniting of Europe: Political, Social, and Economic Forces, 1950-1957. Notre Dame, IN: University of Notre Dame Press.


Haas, E. B. (1961). International integration: The European and the universal process. International Organization, 15(3), 366-392.


Hix, S., & Høyland, B. (2011). The Political System of the European Union, 3rd edition London: Palgrave MacMillan.


Hoffmann, S. (1966). Obstinate or obsolete? The fate of the nation-state and the case of Western Europe. Daedalus, 862-915.


Hooghe, L., & Marks, G. (2003). Unraveling the central state, but how? Types of multi-level governance. American Political Science Review, 97(2), 233-243.


Howarth, D., & Schild, J. (2021). Nein to ‘Transfer Union’: the German brake on the construction of a European Union fiscal capacity. Journal of European Integration, 43(2), 209-226.


Kelemen, R. D. (2000). Regulatory federalism: EU environmental regulation in comparative perspective. Journal of Public Policy, 20(2), 133-167.


Klüver, H. (2013). Lobbying in the European Union: interest groups, lobbying coalitions, and policy change. Oxford: Oxford University Press.


Majone, G. (1994) The rise of the regulatory state in Europe, West European Politics, 17(3), 77-101.


Majone, G. (1996). Regulating Europe. London: Routledge.


Marks, G. (1993). Structural policy and multilevel governance in the EC. In A. Cafruny, & G. Rosenthal (Eds.), The State of the European Community. Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner.


Moravcsik, A. (1993). Preferences and power in the European Community: A liberal intergovernmentalist approach. JCMS: Journal of Common Market Studies, 31(4), 473-524.


Moravcsik, A. (1998). The choice for Europe: Social purpose and state power from Messina to Maastricht.

London: Routledge.


Mourlon-Druol, E. (2012). A Europe Made of Money: The Emergence of the European Monetary System. Cornell, NY: Cornell University Press.


Nugent, N., & Rhinard, M. (2015). The European Commission. London: Macmillan International Higher Education.


Putnam, R. D. (1988). Diplomacy and domestic politics: the logic of two-level games. International Organization, 42(3), 427-460.


Rauh, C. (2019). EU politicization and policy initiatives of the European Commission: The case of consumer policy. Journal of European Public Policy, 26(3), 344-365.


Rhodes, R. A. W. (1997). Understanding governance: Policy networks, governance, reflexivity and accountability. Open University.


Richards, D. & Smith, M. (2004). The hybrid state. In Ludlam, S. & Smith. M. (Eds.) Governing as New Labour. London: Red Globe Press.


Schackel, A. H., Hooghe, L. & Marks, G. (2015). Multilevel governance and the State. In Leibfried, S., Huber, E., Lange, M. Levy, J. D., & Stephen, J. D. (Eds.). The Oxford Handbook of Transformations of the State. Oxford: Oxford University Press.


Scharpf, F. W. (1988). The joint‐decision trap: lessons from German federalism and European integration. Public Administration, 66(3), 239-278.


Simmons, B. A., Dobbin, F., & Garrett, G. (2006). Introduction: The international diffusion of liberalism. International Organization, 60(4), 781-810.


Thomann, E. (2019). Customized implementation of European Union food safety policy: United in diversity? Cham, Switzerland: Palgrave Macmillan.


Tsebelis, G. (1995). Decision making in political systems: Veto players in presidentialism, parliamentarism, multicameralism and multipartyism. British Journal of Political Science, 25(3), 289-325.


Tsebelis, G. (2002). Veto Players. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.



Image References:


Figure 1: Shutterstock (2020). The US is the oldest example of a system of multilevel governance. [Illustration]. Retrieved from: https://www.governing.com/now/the-forgotten-meaning-of-we-the-people.html.


Figure 2: Flickr (n.d.). It's difficult to explain European public policy-making without making any reference to MLG. [Photography]. Retrieved from: https://www.flickr.com/photos/european_parliament/47937867822.


Figure 3: Murphy, M. (2021). Britain has lost the EU. Can it find a role?. [Illustration]. Retrieved from: https://www.economist.com/leaders/2021/01/02/britain-has-lost-the-eu-can-it-find-a-role


Figure 4: Mitchell, J. J. (2022). People manifesting in favour of Scottish independence, which would end its devolution relationship with Westminster. [Photograph]. Retrieved from: https://www.thetimes.co.uk/article/challenge-on-new-scottish-independence-vote-likely-to-end-up-in-court-ckhnscbml.


Cover picture: Bernis, A. (2021). The world is entering a new era of big government. [Illustration]. Retrieved from: https://www.economist.com/leaders/2021/11/20/the-world-is-entering-a-new-era-of-big-government




Comments


Author Photo

Marco Schito

Arcadia _ Logo.png

Arcadia has an extensive catalog of articles on everything from literature to science — all available for free! If you liked this article and would like to read more, subscribe below and click the “Read More” button to discover a world of unique content.

Let the posts come to you!

Thanks for submitting!

  • Instagram
  • Twitter
  • LinkedIn
bottom of page