top of page
Writer's pictureMarco Schito

Public Policy Series: The Public Policy Actors

Foreword


Public policies are everywhere in today’s world, but their ubiquity is also why their definition is often elusive and the analysis of public policies tends to be complex. The Public Policy series offers the reader several tools of analysis that help make sense of the complexity of public policies. This series comprises eight different articles, each focusing on a different aspect, which should provide the reader with a framework of analysis to better understand the complex world of public policy-making.

For each stage of the policy process, some actors may be excluded, while others who were marginal before may become pivotal now (Howlett et al., 2020: 12). This article illustrates how five different categories of actors are differently involved in the policy-making process: politicians (and policy-makers), bureaucrats, interest groups, epistemic communities, and citizens.


Politicians and policy-makers

Politicians and particularly policy-makers are included at all stages of the policy process. They are the only democratically elected actors and are meant to represent the will of the majority of the voters. Politicians contend for power in electoral competitions to pursue specific agendas that align with their beliefs (Hartmann, 2014). These may be, for instance, pro- or anti-market regulation, pro- or anti-immigration, or in the case of European countries, pro- or anti-integration. In some cases, however, scholars contend that the opposite relationship is at play, and that politicians do not win elections in order to enact certain policies: rather, they enact policies to win elections and retain power, thus diluting their ideological content (Downs, 1957).


Politicians can listen to public opinion to decide what to put on the governmental agenda, they formulate and decide on the policies to be enacted, and they direct bureaucrats on how to implement policies. Finally, they can listen to the experts’ evaluation of the enacted policies to decide on whether to continue, modify or terminate a policy. All these actions allow politicians to set the course of a country's political life.


Figure 1: Voting is one of the main ways to achieve policy change [Photo by Marion S. Trikosko]. Source: UnseenHistories on Unsplah

Bureaucrats

Bureaucrats are part of the extended government and constitute the behind-the-scenes arm of politicians. They are often thought to be simply the enactors of governmental agendas, but it needs not to be so. As Page (2003) forcefully argues, civil servants can, for all intents and purposes, assume the role of legislators. They initiate policies by placing them on the political agenda; they make sure that the proposed policies pass through parliament, and they implement and enact them once they have been legitimised. Hence, they are involved at all stages except decision-making, which remains the sole domain of policy-makers.


Their assiduous behind-the-scenes work owes to ministers knowing relatively little about the law they want to advance until civil servants present them with bullet-point briefings and other reports, summarising the key points of the proposals (Page, 2003). But that does not mean that bureaucrats always act at the behest of politicians. As Allison (1969) showed with the different models of management of the Cuban missile crisis, organisations are often messy, and chains of command are not necessarily respected.


Likewise, Carpenter (2001) demonstrated that powerful bureaucrats with a good reputation can also secure policies despite the opposition of politicians. In this regard, the 1980s TV sitcom Yes Minister offered a brilliant example of how civil servants differ from politicians. Finally, a long literature in implementation studies (e.g. Hjern & Hull, 1982; Matland, 1995; Thomann, 2019) shows how bureaucrats have discretion in how policies should be implemented, thus curtailing the power of central policy-makers. Hence, though working in the shadows and anonymously to the public at large, bureaucrats can often exert a significant degree of influence on the political direction of a country.



Figure 2: Sir Humphrey Appleby (in the middle) is the Head of the Civil Service in the British sitcom 'Yes Minister' [Photo]. Source: Foundation for Economic Education

Interest groups

Interest groups are any non-governmental organisation that attempts to influence the policy process to see their interest reflected in the policy output (Chari et al., 2019). They can affect public opinion by setting the agenda, they most often help formulate policies, and they sometimes carry out evaluations thereof to pass on to policy-makers.


Interest groups are also known as lobbies, and constitute perhaps the most reviled aspect of politics (for an example of a scathing critique of a powerful lobby, see Mearsheimer & Walt, 2006). However, this is a distorted perception of what interest groups are and how they work. Chari and Kritzinger (2006) offer a three-fold classification of interest groups: economic, professional, and public groups.


Economic groups are what lobbyists are most commonly assumed to be: powerful business interests that pursue private gain (financial or otherwise) by legitimately interfering with the policy process. According to some authors (Hart, 2004), big business is such a powerful group that it does not work within the logic of typical interest groups. There is much evidence in support of this. An influential but controversial study by Gilens and Page (2014) concludes that ‘economic elites and organized groups representing business interests have substantial independent impacts on U.S. government policy, while average citizens and mass-based interest groups have little or no independent influence.’ For her part, Woll (2019) employs the 2008 economic crisis as a case study to suggest how financial corporations held a privileged status in economic policy-making where they did not even need to exert pressure on policy-makers to obtain what they wanted. As she colourfully describes it, ‘the CEOs and lobbyists of the major financial institutions could have gone off to distant islands slurping cocktails rather than meet with public authorities during the crisis’ (Woll, 2019).



Figure 3: Unknown (2016). Two people shaking hands. [photo]. Lobbyt.com

But not all lobbyists represent private economic interests. Professional groups defend the interest of working categories – lawyers, doctors, teachers, etc. Trade unions are one such group, and in some countries, especially in continental and northern Europe, they have managed to assume a key role in politics and policy-making (see Allern & Bale, 2017; Crepaz, 2020).


Finally, public interest groups are what are commonly known as non-governmental organisations (NGOs). The likes of Greenpeace, Doctors Without Borders, Transparency International or Human Rights Watch are all groups that can contribute to making policy reflect the interest not of the few, but of the many.


Epistemic Communities

Epistemic communities are groups of experts, hailing from academia, research centres and think-tanks, to make a few examples (see Haas, 1992 for a primer on epistemic communities). Like lobbyists, they are mostly involved in the formulation stage of the policy process, where they help policy-makers make informed decisions through what is known as evidence-based policy-making (Cairney, 2016). Unfortunately, given the environment of uncertainty and ambiguity surrounding much policy-making, epistemic communities have so far had little success in strongly influencing policy (Cairney & Kwiatowski, 2017).


Experts can also contribute significantly to policy evaluation and impact assessment (e.g. Dunlop et al., 2012). In a turn of irony, Dunlop (2017) also describes how epistemic communities, by generating new knowledge for policy evaluations and recommendations that supersede old knowledge (which they themselves had created), may also be curtailing their very policy-making influence.



Figure 4: Animal activist at the London Fashion Week [Photo by Clem Onojeghuo]. Source: Unsplash

Public opinion and voters

Although voters are often identified with the ‘governed’ rather than the ‘governing’, they can exert important influence in policy-making. The most obvious way is through voting, although this influence is merely indirect. Rather, they have much more say during the agenda-setting stage. Here, public opinion can open up the window of opportunity for policy-makers to act (Mortensen, 2010; Green-Pedersen & Mortensen, 2018). Recent examples are the economic sanctions against Russia or the ‘green turn’ in several policies: both of them were in part driven by the changing public opinion and higher sensibilisation of voters to these new issues.


Another way in which voters can have a more direct influence on policy-making is through referenda (on this, see Gallagher, 2014). Referenda are commonplace in direct democracy countries such as Switzerland, but can be employed every now and then everywhere else, although their results seldom bind policy-makers. The most famous example is Brexit (which, ironically, was not binding), but others include the legalisation of marijuana in certain US states, and the ban on fracking in several countries.


Other policy-making actors

In some countries, there are other actors that do not fall within any of the five aforementioned categories but that can still exert important policy-making power. The most famous and important one is the US Supreme Court. In light of the common law system of the American judiciary, the Court holds important quasi-law-making powers. Among the most widely known decisions are Brown v. Board of Education (1954), which declared segregation in education illegal, and Roe v. Wade (1973) which ensured abortion could be performed safely and legally, but also Citizens United (2010), which granted an almost citizen-like status to corporations (money as free speech), and Shelby County v. Holder (2013), which rolled back some provisions from the Voting Rights Acts of the 1960s.



Figure 5: A drawing depicting the nine US Justices, a powerful force in quasi-law-making in the United States [Drawing]. Source: NPR

Conclusion

In sum, a wide range of actors can exert influence in policy-making, but not all to the same extent, nor during the same stage of the policy process. While citizens are loudest in the agenda-setting stage, interest groups can best influence the formulation of policies, which policy-makers must vote on. Bureaucrats have the most discretion in implementation, and experts play an important role in policy evaluation and learning.


Bibliographical references


Allern E.H., Bale T. (2017). Left-of-Centre Parties and Trade Unions in the Twenty-First Century. Oxford: Oxford University Press.


Allison, G. T. (1969). Conceptual models and the Cuban missile crisis. American Political Science Review, 63(3), 689-718.


Cairney, P. (2016). The Politics of Evidence-Based Policymaking. London: Palgrave Pivot.


Cairney, P., & Kwiatkowski, R. (2017). How to communicate effectively with policymakers: combine insights from psychology and policy studies. Science Communications, 3(1), 1-8.


Carpenter, D. P. (2001). The Forging of Bureaucratic Autonomy. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.


Chari, R., & Kritzinger, S. (2006). Understanding EU policy making. London: Pluto Press.


Chari, R., Hogan, J., Murphy, G. and Crepaz, M. (2019). Regulating Lobbying. A Global Comparison, 2nd edition. Manchester: Manchester University Press.


Crepaz, M. (2021). How parties and interest groups protect their ties: The case of lobbying laws. Regulation & Governance, 15(4), 1370-1387.


Downs, A. (1957). An economic theory of democracy. New York: Harper.


Dunlop, C. A. (2017). The irony of epistemic learning: epistemic communities, policy learning and the case of Europe’s hormones saga. Policy and Society, 36(2), 215-232.


Dunlop, C. A., Maggetti, M., Radaelli, C. M., & Russel, D. (2012). The many uses of regulatory impact assessment: A meta‐analysis of EU and UK cases. Regulation & Governance, 6(1), 23-45.


Gallagher, M. (2014). Elections and Referendums. In Comparative Politics, 3rd Edition. Caramani, D. (Ed.) Oxford: Oxford University Press.


Gilens, M., & Page, B. I. (2014). Testing theories of American politics: Elites, interest groups, and average citizens. Perspectives on politics, 12(3), 564-581.


Green-Pedersen, C. and Mortensen, P. B.. (2018). Attention, politics and the public. In Routledge Handbook of Public Policy. Araral, E. Jr, Fritzen, S., Howlett, M. and Ramesh, M. (Eds.). London and New York, NY: Routledge, pp. 167-174.


Haas, P. M. (1992). Introduction: epistemic communities and international policy coordination. International Organization, 46(1), 1-35.


Hart, D. M. (2004). " Business" Is Not An Interest Group: On the Study of Companies in American National Politics. Annual Review of Political Science, 7, 47-69.


Hartmann, S. (2014). Partisan policy-making in Western Europe: How ideology influences the content of government policies. Mannheim: Springer.


Hjern, B., & Hull, C. (1982). Implementation research as empirical constitutionalism. European Journal of Political Research, 10(2), 105-115.


Howlett, M., Ramesh M., and Perl, A. (2020). Studying Public Policy. Principles and Processes. 4th edition. Oxford: Oxford University Press.


Matland, R. E. (1995). Synthesizing the implementation literature: The ambiguity-conflict model of policy implementation. Journal of Public Administration Research and Rheory, 5(2), 145-174.


Mearsheimer, J., & Walt, S. (2006). The Israel Lobby. London Review of Books, 28(6), 3-12.


Mortensen, P. B. (2010). Political attention and public policy: A study of how agenda setting matters. Scandinavian Political Studies, 33(4), 356-380.


Page, E. C. (2003). The civil servant as legislator: law making in British administration. Public administration, 81(4), 651-679.


Thomann, E. (2019). Customized implementation of European Union food safety policy: United in diversity? Cham, Switzerland: Palgrave Macmillan.


Woll, C. (2019). Corporate power beyond lobbying. American Affairs, 3(3), 38-55.


Image references


Figure 1: Unsplash (n.d.) Marchers with signs at the March on Washington, 1963 [Photo by Marion S. Trikosko]. Retrieved from: https://unsplash.com/photos/9RbdjQ3nCEk


Figure 2: Foundation for Economic Education (2018, November 18th). Still from the TV series Yes Minister [Photo]. Retrieved from: https://fee.org/articles/the-bbcs-yes-minister-is-everything-you-need-to-know-about-government/


Unknown (2016). Two people shaking hands. [photo]. Lobbyt.com https://lobbyit.com/things-consider-hiring-lobbyist/


Figure 4: Unsplash (n.d.) Animal activist at the London Fashion Week [Photo by Clem Onojeghuo]. Retrieved from: https://unsplash.com/photos/DoA2duXyzRM


Figure 5: NPR (2020, December 10th). Depiction of the nine US Justices [Drawing]. Retrieved from: https://www.npr.org/2020/12/07/943937968/supreme


Comments


Author Photo

Marco Schito

Arcadia _ Logo.png

Arcadia has an extensive catalog of articles on everything from literature to science — all available for free! If you liked this article and would like to read more, subscribe below and click the “Read More” button to discover a world of unique content.

Let the posts come to you!

Thanks for submitting!

  • Instagram
  • Twitter
  • LinkedIn
bottom of page